Graduates celebrate breaking drug addiction

The City of Cape Town’s Health Department not only celebrated the graduation of those who have completed the Matrix® Programme at its eight sites this year, but also the programme’s 83% clean drug test rate.

The City’s substance abuse programme is open to anyone over 18 and follows the evidence-based Matrix® model.

Treatment consists of three to four sessions a week including counselling for clients and their families, skills that help clients stay sober, a relapse prevention group focusing on living without alcohol and drugs as well as a social support group.

‘Substance abuse continues to wreak havoc on individuals, households and communities. I commend those who have tackled their addiction by seeking help through the Matrix® programme and who want to change their lives for the better. It takes courage to admit you have a problem and even greater bravery to step forward and actively do something about it.  We can only help those who are serious about helping themselves,’ said the City’s Mayoral Committee Member for Community Services and Health, Councillor Patricia van der Ross.

For the first nine months of this year, 2 050 people were screened in the programme with just more than two-thirds being men.

The City of Cape Town first introduced the substance abuse treatment programme in 2008, with the launch of the first facility in Tafelsig, with sites following in Delft South, Town Two in Khayelitsha, Albow Gardens in Milnerton, Parkwood, Manenberg, Eerste River and Scottsdene.

The main substances of choice are Tik, dagga and alcohol.

Councillor Ronel Viljoen, Chairperson of the Community Services and Health Portfolio Committee, attended the graduation and encouraged the graduates to stay the course.

‘The festive season is a difficult time for people in recovery. The holiday mood; parties and stress around this time of year, may increase the risk of relapse. It is important to have a plan; schedule time; speak to your counsellor; continue attending support groups; find fun things and old hobbies to do that can take the place of substance use.  The Matrix® sites will remain open during the festive season so that those who need help can access the help that they need,’ added Councillor Viljoen.

Caption 1: At the ceremony were Zukiswa Mandlana the Executive Director for Community Services and Health, Fiona Matthee, Councillor Ronel Viljoen, Ameerah van Reenen and Councillor Patricia van der Ross.

Caption 2: Portia Mbebe, in the middle, received a certificate for early recovery. On her left is Dr. Lenny Naidoo Manager: Specialised Health and on the right is Councillor Patricia van der Ross.

Source: City Of Cape Town

City invites graduates to apply for SCM internship programme

The City is looking for qualified graduates to apply for its Supply Chain Management (SCM) Graduate Internship Programme. Ten positions have been created and the closing date for applications is Monday, 14 November 2022.

‘The internship opportunities begin in February next year, for suitably qualified graduates in the fields of Finance, Supply Chain Management, Law, and the Built Environment. The purpose of this programme is to provide graduates with the opportunity to learn from experts in their field, and to build capacity within our Supply Chain Management department. Successful applicants will be appointed on a three-year contract, which will give them the opportunity to acquire valuable skills and experience in this increasingly sought-after field.

‘Supply chain management is critical to project and service delivery in the City, and requires highly professional and skilled staff to manage the procurement value chain. The City of Cape Town is developing a Centre of Excellence within its supply chain, and is constantly looking at ways to improve and refine its systems, and increase professional capacity. A well-run, efficient and effective system adds value to the public and the procurement of goods and services for the City’s residents, and is a cornerstone of our Vision for a City of Hope.

‘The City has recognised the need to nurture and develop fresh young talent to improve capacity and ensure that it keeps growing and improving in this highly complex and regulated environment,’ said the City’s Mayoral Committee Member for Finance, Councillor Siseko Mbandezi.

‘This programme is very close to the heartbeat of the City’s determination to offer employment and training to individuals in a meaningful way. We welcome applications for the 10 paid internships, and encourage qualified applicants to make sure they apply before the deadline,’ said the City’s Mayoral Committee Member for Corporate Services, Alderman Theresa Uys.

Applicants may apply online at www.capetown.gov.za/careers. Applicants must be recent graduates of a tertiary institution, and be in possession of a recognised degree or diploma in one of the relevant fields. In order to be considered, applications must be sent through by 14 November 2022.

Source: City Of Cape Town

Public urged to support matrics

The Department of Basic Education has appealed to members of the public to support learners and refrain from blockading roads and storming schools as the country enters another week of the National Senior Certificate (NSC) examinations.

The department has also appealed to learners to stop bringing crib notes and cell phones into the examination centres.

Director-General of the Department of Basic Education, Mathanzima Mweli, appealed to members of the community to allow the examinations to proceed.  

The Director-General was speaking at a technical media briefing on the state of the progress of the National Senior Certificate examinations for the Class of 2022.

“The repercussions for not doing so are devastating to the learners and the communities themselves ,as it is the children of the same communities that suffer the consequences.

“In cases where learners are not able to write examinations, it means that they will rewrite the missed papers only in May/June next year. That is not fair on the learners, who have already endured a lot as a result of COVID-19, among other challenges,” Mweli said.

This comes after 53 learners from Etwatwa in Gauteng could not write exams, as there were gunshots fired in the area they were in.

There were also disruptions in parts of the Northern Cape, even though writing eventually took place but the environment has not been conducive.

Mweli said the department has also had to deal with cases where some schools denied learners the right to sit for the NSC exams because they are pregnant.

“The National Policy on the Prevention and Management of Learner Pregnancy states expressly that barring a learner from school on the grounds of pregnancy is discriminatory.

“A learner who is pregnant shall be allowed to sit for national examinations if her health condition permits,” Mweli said.

He said the school principal and staff, in collaboration with parents/guardians, shall take all reasonable steps to accommodate the learner’s learning, health and maternal needs during the examination period.

Irregularities

The department has further urged candidates and any other person who comes across any irregularities related to the current National Senior Certificate examinations to report to the department immediately.

Mweli said irregularities can be reported on the dedicated 24-hour WhatsApp line on 069 335 2818.

The Director-General thanked all officials involved in the administration of the NSC examinations for the sterling work done under difficult conditions.

He acknowledged that the rainy season does not make it any easier either but the department prays that it does not escalate into a crisis.

“We wish to also thank our sister departments such as SAPS, Defence, Health, Social Development, Weather Services and others who are always available to provide support,” he said.

Source: South African Government News Agency

Governor Lesetja Kganyago: Public lecture at Wits School of Governance

Public lecture by Lesetja Kganyago, Governor of the South African Reserve Bank, at the Wits School of Governance Johannesburg

Keeping it simple: monetary policy, growth and jobs in South Africa

Introduction

Good morning, ladies and gentlemen.

Central banks are important, long-standing expressions of a universal need for stability in social and economic affairs. Their goals centre on achieving some definition of price stability, and in more recent decades, their methods have fixed primarily on inflation targeting.

Where they directly target inflation, central banks’ primary tool is the policy rate, normally defined as a very short-term or overnight borrowing rate. At this rate, banks can borrow from the central bank to address overnight needs for liquidity and this marginal borrowing rate sets the basis for all other lending rates in the economy. A secondary policy tool is a blend of communications about current economic conditions and the policy rate level.  A third encompasses the requirements and flexibility of the policy framework – the target itself and how it is measured.

In more recent years, and under the impact of deflationary conditions, a few advanced economy central banks have adapted their approaches with secondary targets, such as inflation averages over time and unemployment rates.

Today, I want to spend some time unpacking why it is useful for the South African Reserve Bank (SARB), and most emerging economies generally, to target inflation, and why achieving that goal ensures that monetary policy includes economic growth and job creation.

I will look at recent changes in policy targets for the moment, before returning to current conditions and the relevance of jobs and growth targets for monetary policy.

Financial distress, deflation and policy exceptionalism

It is useful to start with the global economic shocks of the past 15 years and their monetary policy implications.

While the global financial crisis (GFC) and the COVID-19 pandemic had different origins, the economic policy responses to them were similar.  Advanced economies reacted to both by dropping interest rates as far as possible and using quantitative easing (QE).  During the GFC, QE programmes kept asset prices of various kinds higher than they would otherwise have been, preventing asset price deflation from causing even worse economic outcomes. During the pandemic, QE additionally supported spending, as mobility and many face-to-face economic transactions were curtailed, while also protecting financial institutions.

Job protection was also a major focus for major central banks and job creation became a measure of their policy effectiveness. More liquidity would help keep interest rates low, enabling firms to keep paying wages and to restart the economy.

What impact have these efforts made on policy frameworks? Certainly, where countries faced collapsing growth and weaker inflation together, they could all move policy in the same direction. However, when the GFC ended and the pandemic ended, not all faced the same policy trade-offs.  The GFC ushered in an extended period of ongoing QE and low rates, but this was not true for most emerging market economies. The end of the pandemic has been different. It has thrown us all back into a pre-Great Moderation world in which inflation is super-sensitive to supply and demand shocks.

In particular, and with the benefit of hindsight, the current global inflation finds much of its origin in a too aggressive use of QE and in negative real rates as the pandemic started to wind down and economic activity rose.  As in emerging economies post- GFC, many countries now, post-pandemic, find their output gaps to be badly measured and giving off incorrect signals about their policy stance.

As, and if, the current surge in global inflation wanes, some advanced economies may very well return to lower inflation for structural and demographic reasons.  These central banks may retain other metrics in their policy frameworks – such as economic growth rates or the prices of specific assets (e.g. house prices in New Zealand), or in the case of the United States (US), employment levels.

But it is highly unlikely that emerging market economies will decide to change their policy frameworks. Many had reverted to much higher inflation even before the pandemic eased, while others, like South Africa, are now caught up in broader inflation.  In that more normal context, the standard monetary policy approaches make as much of a positive impact on economic growth and jobs as they can. However, the real solutions to faster growth and job creation lie in other policy domains.

Why the difference between advanced and emerging economies?   Why might the rules governing  objectives differ  somewhat? The answer has to do with  pure economic theory, actual experience, and with the different economic conditions − cyclical and structural − faced by different central banks.

To begin, it should be clear that for quite some time, essentially since the early 2000s, central banks of advanced economies have faced stubbornly low inflation, despite low interest rates, for a range of structural reasons related primarily to demographics and high savings. So, when they took an accommodative stance to raise growth and employment levels during the Great Moderation of the 2000s and the period into the pandemic, inflation still remained modest.

As the pandemic hit, because inflation remained low, there was as yet no contradiction between the inflation targets and boosting growth.  Policy expansion could help get people who had dropped out of the labour market back in.  Job creation was efficient. Expansionary stances worked well with strategies that lowered the cost to firms of retaining people in jobs.

In South Africa’s case, the pandemic also facilitated expansionary policy, precisely because inflation had trended lower from 2017.  This allowed us to lower policy rates sharply in 2020 to confront the shorter-term damage done to the economy. The repurchase (repo) rate averaged 6.7% between 2017 and early 2020, before dropping to 3.5% in March/April of that year.

A deeper dive into jobs and growth targets

As in advanced economies, our expansion did little to immediately bring back jobs. Many were lost as lockdowns were extended, while some new ones were created in various services linked to the shift in consumption patterns.  Expansion did support the recovery of both pre-pandemic spending patterns and many of the jobs associated with them.  Of course, there is also much further to go, as some sectors remain constrained.

The open question is whether sustained expansion in an environment of high debt levels and rising inflation could live up to the hopes of those that argue for a ‘jobs’ mandate for monetary policy.  The short answer is ‘no’, but let me explain why.

Our basic problem is that while growth creates job, inflation does not.  Not only does this fatally challenge the belief many hold in the existence of usable Phillips curves, but it also limits what macroeconomic policy can achieve in terms of job creation.  As we have noted many times in the past, the solutions to our unemployment problem lie well outside the realm of monetary policy, and in fact the failure to employ those solutions directly limits the positive contribution monetary policy can play.

Let’s look at what the historical data tell us about Phillips curves.  We see two correlations.   One is that as inflation rises, unemployment rates rise.   This characterises the late 1990s and into the latter half of 2003.  In 2002/03, for example, inflation reached double digits even while employment was falling – when unemployment breached 30%.

From about 2003 to 2007, however, we see another correlation, where inflation falls and employment rises.  After the GFC, from about 2011 to 2019, we see something different. Inflation first came off the highs of the GFC and then accelerated back up to around 6%.  There was some initial recovery in jobs, but as time went on, the acceleration was increasingly located in the public sector rather than the private sector.  Economic growth weakened quite sharply from 2013 to 2015 and then more gradually slowed through to the pandemic. From 2017 onwards, inflation decelerated and so did job creation.

The GFC and the pandemic were relatively clear instances when policy could respond in textbook ways to support the economy and see-through inflation shocks.  Before and after these crises, we see more transparently the longer-term relationships between inflation and job creation.  First, inflation does not create jobs. And second, on balance, expansionary policy prompts more inflation than growth or job creation.

This tells us that South Africa’s Phillips curve is near-vertical at a low rate of positive economic growth.

This is strong evidence that the basic job creation mechanism is being impeded by things other than aggregate demand.

This adverse relationship between policy expansion and inflation kicks in when employment levels rise above what is called the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, or NAIRU.  Evidence for South Africa shows that this happens when our unemployment rate is still very high.  This is exacerbated by level changes in the NAIRU caused by structural impediments to job creation. For instance, load-shedding or higher transport costs indirectly increase the cost of creating jobs and push up the NAIRU.

A range of long-standing factors contribute to our very high NAIRU. Perhaps the most important of these is where people live and the cost of supplying their labour, and the skills they have compared to their cost.8  Regulatory costs of our economy also feature in various ways, including housing, where businesses can ply their trade, and compliance − which is a much larger burden for small and medium-sized businesses compared to that of larger firms.

Part of the difficulty is that we have done little to make it easier for less-skilled workers to find jobs, or to make it less costly to employ them.

Another part of the failing job creation machine is simply weaker real economic growth compared to the 2000s, when job creation was quite strong.

This should not, however, lead us down the path of grasping at another seemingly ‘easy’ answer. Higher inflation will not give us higher sustainable growth.

Instead, higher inflation undermines short-run growth by increasing interest rates on borrowing, affecting consumers’ buying on credit and business owners who want to use credit to invest. Higher interest costs reduce short-run cash flow, reducing all future consumption spending.

While surprise inflation reduces the real value of the existing stock of debt owed, the trade-off is lower economic growth in subsequent years.  The short-run benefit of a surprise lower interest rate is transformed by higher inflation into a long-run cost to growth.

When inflation is higher than that of our trading partners, we suffer a continuous loss of competitiveness.  High inflation overall also generally means higher inflation for poorer and less-skilled South Africans than for the wealthy. This increases inequality further and worsens the already low standard of living for those households, making them costlier to employ.

For a few years before the GFC in 2008, the relationship between growth and employment was better – if economic activity grew by 1%, employment grew by around 0.62%. But since then, up to 2018, each percentage point improvement in growth only gives us 0.37% more jobs. Our low employment problem overlaps entirely with our low growth problem.

In this context, the best a central bank can do is stabilise unemployment at the rate consistent with price stability. If a central bank attempts to get unemployment below the NAIRU, the result will be larger quantities of inflation but only small and temporary quantities of jobs as the supply curve becomes more vertical. The same is true for economic growth.

Assuming that most of our unemployment problem is structural, are we at least sure that the residual cyclical unemployment is being reduced by monetary policy?  Is a dual mandate better at addressing these cyclical drivers?

At the SARB, we use an alternative measure of economic activity to the NAIRU for understanding where the economy is relative to its tipping point into more inflation or into deflation. This is the output gap, or the distance between the possible, or potential, growth rate of the economy and the actual or realised rate of growth.

Similar to the US Federal Reserve (Fed), we use a Taylor rule to help tell us what the interest rate level should be, given the output gap and the distance between the inflation rate we want (the target) and where it currently is. 13   The Taylor rule tells us that we should set an interest rate that includes how quickly or slowly the economy is growing, compared to the speed at which it could be growing.

If the output gap is a good representative measure of the cyclical unemployment rate, then we are fully covered – the monetary policy equation we use to get to the interest rate includes, as best we can, the relationship between those rates and employment. If we look at how the Fed operates, we can take further comfort in our own framework. The Fed has an inflation target of 2%, averaged over time. This averaging introduces some flexibility to not respond to inflation shocks that are temporary, just as in our flexible inflation-targeting framework. But the Fed framework does not say that when unemployment rises it will aim for a higher inflation rate.  In other words, the dual mandate recognises that in the long run, the highest cyclical employment rate is consistent with low inflation.  In the policy debate at present in the US, there may be a rise in cyclical unemployment to get inflation back down and to achieve a lower sustainable unemployment rate.

We need also to be cautious in our current circumstances.  With surging inflation in advanced economies, it is likely that the adjusted policy frameworks of recent times will shift back to simpler and clearer formulations.

Three takeaways from this discussion stand out. One is that inflation-targeting central banks also consider real variables such as growth and unemployment when they make monetary policy decisions.  Second, that central banks don’t drop targeting inflation, even if they have an employment mandate.  It simply means they respect the NAIRU and discuss more directly its level and what can happen to inflation when the speed limit implied by it is exceeded. And third, that despite some policy innovation in recent times in some advanced economies, these may very well be scaled back to simpler frameworks.

Finally, we need to recognise, for the sake of solving our low employment problem and to keep monetary policy focused on the right things, that many issues sharply limit the transmission from policy to job creation outcomes. One is the job intensity of growth which we discussed. Another is the supply of skills that are coming into the market, and their cost.

Some might argue that in that case, it means that monetary policy should be pushed much further and harder to get the expected growth or jobs. Unfortunately, when inefficiencies and constraints exist, pushing harder on monetary policy is like pushing the accelerator to the floor on a curvy, icy road over a mountain pass.  At present, many central banks are skidding on that ice, with global inflation sharply higher and persistent.  Even our own relatively benign recent inflation experience has become much more challenging very quickly.

Keeping it simple

We have seen now that having two targets certainly does not mean double the benefit. Instead, it means that there are times and certain conditions when one policy tool helps to achieve both.  It also means that under other conditions, one tool cannot achieve both, and much of the world has now entered this territory.

When policy becomes overloaded with too many and contradictory objectives, then negative outcomes are more likely.

As inflation rises and growth slows, a central bank that fails to respond to rising prices will face the prospect of compounding inflationary shocks. Currencies depreciate and investment falls. 14

So where, in all of this, does South Africa find itself? We have not reached the ‘end’ of our policy rate space. We do not have stubbornly low or close to zero inflation.  We are experiencing rising inflation rates. Inflation expectations, for the most part, are proving to be more responsive to current inflation outcomes than we would like, and less anchored around the midpoint of our target.

If the expectations that firms and households hold for future inflation stray from the inflation target, then higher nominal wages and consumer prices are likely to emerge. In other words, once inflation expectations rise, they become a self-fulfilling prophecy, and the central bank has a more difficult and longer-term problem on its hands. A more expansionary policy stance runs that risk by enabling first-round inflation to embed into second-round inflation.

This implies that we need to continue the normalisation of interest rates, moving them closer to the level that is consistent with more stable inflation rates and sustainable economic growth.  At present, our repo rate is at 6.25%, still below long-term levels, but  rising  to  a more sustainable  long-term  level  that is  consistent  with inflation stabilising at 4.5%.

Conclusion

As we have discussed today, neither growth nor high inflation lead directly to job creation in our economy. Much of our employment challenge lies in encouraging the return of economic activity in sectors that have been hardest hit by the pandemic. And we will also need to recognise that some jobs may be permanently lost as firms do things differently and as consumption patterns shift.  Other jobs will be gained, however, and permanently impacting on employment levels requires approaches that have nothing to do with monetary policy. Just adding jobs targets will not get us there, and indeed part of our inflation problem stems from efforts to achieve such targets at a global level.

We should be careful not to add to our policy objectives in a way that surely would push us into sharply higher inflation.

If these are the primary constraints to job creation defined by the literature, and monetary policy has no impact on them, then the claim that more expansionary policies will solve the unemployment problem is simply an empty promise, backed up by little more than ideology and wishful thinking.

We have an unemployment problem that needs more credible solutions.

Employment and growth are both limited by factors that are beyond the reach of the central bank’s toolset.

The best chance we have with monetary policy to get faster, more job-rich growth is to maintain our focus on price stability with flexible inflation targeting − a proven framework. This enables the SARB to help maintain a stable environment that is conducive to economic growth, and because credibility is high, for it to create the necessary flexibility to ignore short-term inflation shocks.

A credible monetary policy will also keep borrowing costs lower than they would otherwise be. This is a central benefit to long-term economic growth and job creation. When inflation rises and stays high, investment decisions are distorted towards short- term investments that carry with them short-term jobs. For this reason, low inflation is a sound developmental policy.  It encourages firms across the private and public sector to make long-term investment decisions that imply productivity growth over time. This is critical, indeed a prerequisite, for sustainable jobs and income growth.

Consumption based on rising debt levels cannot be a sustainable growth and development strategy.

Having faced the unique threat of the COVID-19 crisis, we confronted that challenge with relatively low stable inflation and policy rate space. We were able to soften the damage of the crisis with the policy rate, while still protecting the value of the rand, and in so doing, were able to play our part in maintaining macroeconomic stability.

Now that the global economy is recovering and inflation in many countries, including our own, is rising, we have learned from experience that we must not be tempted to loosen our grip on inflation, or to fall behind our peers as rates are normalised – the consequences would be too costly.

Source: Government of South Africa

Day 2 of matric examinations

The Department of Basic Education says it is pleased that the first official day of the 2022 National Senior Certificate (NSC) Examinations has gone without major challenges.

More than 794 000 candidates sat for the 2-hour English Paper 1 in 6 800 centres around the country yesterday.

Despite the rain in parts of KwaZulu-Natal there were no reported disruptions in all provinces.

Basic Education Minister Angie Motshekga praised the Class of 2022 for their resilience and perseverance.

She said the Class of 2022 was the worst affected in terms of the impact of COVID-19. She appealed to South Africans to continue to support the NSC candidates throughout the exam period which ends in the first week of December.

Today, more than 165 360 candidates will write Economics P1, also a 2-hour paper.

Source: South African Government News Agency

MEC David Maynier on the delay in construction of Manenberg School of Skills

Another delay in the construction of Manenberg School of Skills

Last month, I announced that the construction mafia had interrupted work on the new Manenberg School of Skills, an R84 million project scheduled to take 87 weeks to complete.

Unfortunately, another delay over which the Western Cape Education Department (WCED) has no control, has now struck the build. A company that was not awarded the tender, initiated an interdict and review application against the award of the tender contract.

Building of the school has been interdicted pending the hearing of the review application, on 24 November 2022 by the Western Cape High Court.

The result is that the community will, unfortunately, have to wait even longer for the school to be completed, and that there will be a delay in us providing desperately needed School of Skills places in Manenberg.

Schools of Skills offer learners who would otherwise potentially drop out of the mainstream academic curriculum the opportunity to pursue their own passion in a skills education environment.

We currently have 25 Schools of Skills in our province, and another 2 public ordinary schools with a School of Skills stream. They offer a variety of skills subjects, from electrical work to hairdressing and everything in between, along with traditional academic subjects to give learners a well-rounded skills education.

Their success has resulted in strong demand for placement in these schools which vastly outstrips the available places we have so far. We must increase the number of schools and places available, and Manenberg School of Skills is a vital part of this expansion of places.

Yet, while we are doing our very best to build new schools more quickly to meet the continued demand for places in our province, the people of Manenberg will now have to wait even longer for their children to have this opportunity, which is very disappointing for the community, and very disappointing for the Department.

We are working hard to fast track construction and engaging with our local and provincial government partners to speed up delivery, so we call on all residents to work with us so that we can deliver additional school places in the communities where they are needed.

Source: Government of South Africa

Nzimande sends condolences to families of Stellenbosch University students

Higher Education, Science and Innovation Minister, Dr Blade Nzimande has sent his heartfelt condolences to the families of two University of Stellenbosch students whose bodies were found in a quarry in Stellenbosch.

Ethan Kirkland aged 19 and Leila Lees aged 18, both first-year Bachelor of Science students at Stellenbosch University, went missing last week Friday and their bodies were found on Monday.

According to the law enforcement report, the students’ lives ended in tragedy when their vehicle submerged in a quarry with both the students still inside at Paul Kruger Street in Stellenbosch.

The two were declared dead by medical personnel on the scene.

Nzimande expressed his is appreciation to community member who spotted the vehicle in the dam and reported it to law enforcement agencies.

He also commended the swift response from the law enforcement agencies and the emergency services who retrieved the vehicle from the dam and identified the victims.

“I call upon the law enforcement agencies to further investigate circumstances that might have led to Ethan and Leila vehicle’s being submerged in the dam,” Nzimande said in a statement.

The Minister also appealed to the students to be more circumspect in and off campus particularly at this time of the year when final examinations are underway and institutions preparing to close the academic year activities.

Nzimande has directed Higher Health – the Department of Higher Education and Training agency responsible for the welfare of both students and staff – to work together with the Stellenbosch University to provide the necessary comfort including psychosocial services to the families, friends and lecturers of the deceased students.

Source: South African Government News Agency